A longitudinal study of self-selection, learning-by-exporting and core-competence: The case of smalland medium-sized enterprises in Vietnam
Based on longitudinal data from biennial surveys of small- and medium- sized enterprises (SMEs) in
Vietnam conducted from 2007 to 2013, we find supports to the self-selection and learning-by-exporting
hypotheses. We find that the SMEs having higher sunk costs and capital size are more likely to become
exporters. Applying the propensity score matching method in combination with the Difference-inDifference estimation, the study finds that export has raised SMEs’ productivity measured by either
TFP or labor productivity, sales revenue, and value added of the SMEs. Furthermore, the gains from
learning-by-exporting and specializing in core-competence products were stronger in the early years
of entry into the export markets. These findings suggest policies to promote export of SMEs in an
appropriate timing
Trang 1
Trang 2
Trang 3
Trang 4
Trang 5
Trang 6
Trang 7
Trang 8
Trang 9
Trang 10
Tải về để xem bản đầy đủ
Tóm tắt nội dung tài liệu: A longitudinal study of self-selection, learning-by-exporting and core-competence: The case of smalland medium-sized enterprises in Vietnam
resources towards their core-competence, which are in labor-intensive products. Participation of the SMEs in exporting has not yet increased Vietnamese SMEs' capital intensity. Instead, the focus of the SMEs has been still on labor-intensive industries, of which the competitive advantages come from labor abundance and low- wages in transition economies like Vietnam. Acknowledgements This research is funded by Vietnam National Foundation for Science and Technology Development (NAFOSTED) under grant number 502.01-2018.03. References Alegre, J., & Chiva, R. (2008). Assessing the impact of organizational learning capability on product innovation performance: An empirical test. Technovation, 28(6), 315-326. Alvarez, R., & Lopez, R. A. (2005). Exporting and performance: evidence from Chilean plants. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique, 38(4), 1384-1400. Arnold, J. M., & Hussinger, K. (2005). Export behavior and firm productivity in German manufacturing: A firm-level analysis. Review of World Economics, 141(2), 219-243. Arrow, K. J. (1971). The economic implications of learning by doing. In Readings in the Theory of Growth (pp. 131-149). Palgrave Macmillan, London. Aw, B. Y., Chen, X., & Roberts, M. J. (2001). Firm-level evidence on productivity differentials and turnover in Taiwanese manufacturing. Journal of Development Economics, 66(1), 51-86. Baldwin, J. R., & Gu, W. (2003). Export‐market participation and productivity performance in Canadian manufacturing. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique, 36(3), 634-657. Baldwin, R. (1988). Hysteresis in import prices: the beachhead effect (No. w2545). National Bureau of Economic Research. Baldwin, R., & Krugman, P. (1989). Persistent trade effects of large exchange rate shocks. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104(4), 635-654. Becker, S. O., & Ichino, A. (2002). Estimation of average treatment effects based on propensity scores. The Stata Journal, 2(4), 358-377. Bernard, A. B., Jensen, J. B., & Lawrence, R. Z. (1995). Exporters, jobs, and wages in US manufacturing: 1976-1987. Brookings papers on economic activity. Microeconomics, 1995, 67-119. Bernard, A. B., & Jensen, J. B. (1999). Exceptional exporter performance: cause, effect, or both?. Journal of international economics, 47(1), 1-25. Bernard, A. B., & Jensen, J. B. (2004). Why some firms export. Review of economics and Statistics, 86(2), 561-569. Bernard, A. B., & Jensen, J. B. (2004). Exporting and Productivity in the USA. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 20(3), 343- 357. Bernard, A. B., Redding, S. J., & Schott, P. K. (2011). Multiproduct firms and trade liberalization. The Quarterly journal of economics, 126(3), 1271-1318. Castellani, D. (2002). Export behavior and productivity growth: Evidence from Italian manufacturing firms. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 138(4), 605-628. Clerides, S. K., Lach, S., & Tybout, J. R. (1998). Is learning by exporting important? Micro-dynamic evidence from Colombia, Mexico, and Morocco. The quarterly journal of economics, 113(3), 903-947. Doan, N. T., Nguyen, K. T., & Mai, P. C. (2020). The effects of cash in advance on export decision: the case of Vietnam. Journal of International Economics and Management, 20(1), 1-12. De Loecker, J. (2007). Do exports generate higher productivity? Evidence from Slovenia. Journal of international economics, 73(1), 69-98. 490 Delgado, M. A., Farinas, J. C., & Ruano, S. (2002). Firm productivity and export markets: a non-parametric approach. Journal of international Economics, 57(2), 397-422. Dixit, A. (1989). Hysteresis, import penetration, and exchange rate pass-through. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104(2), 205-228. Eckel, C., & Neary, J. P. (2010). Multi-product firms and flexible manufacturing in the global economy. The Review of Economic Studies, 77(1), 188-217. Feenstra, R., & Ma, H. (2007). Optimal choice of product scope for multiproduct firms under monopolistic competition (No. w13703). National Bureau of Economic Research. Feenstra, R. C., Li, Z., & Yu, M. (2014). Exports and credit constraints under incomplete information: Theory and evidence from China. Review of Economics and Statistics, 96(4), 729-744. Feng, D., Chen, Q., Song, M., & Cui, L. (2019). Relationship between the degree of internationalization and performance in manufacturing enterprises of the Yangtze river delta region. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, 55(7), 1455-1471. Fernandes, A. M., & Isgut, A. E. (2015). Learning-by-exporting effects: are they for real?. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, 51(1), 65-89. Filipescu, D. A., Rialp, A., & Rialp, J. (2009). Internationalisation and technological innovation: empirical evidence on their mutual relationship. Advances in International Marketing, 20, 125-154. Fornes, G., & Cardoza, G. (2019). Internationalization of Chinese SMEs: The perception of disadvantages of foreignness. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, 55(9), 2086-2105. General Statistics Office (2017). Vietnam's Exports and Imports of Goods- International Integration and Development. Hanoi: Statistical Publishing House. Girma, S., Greenaway, A., & Kneller, R. (2004). Does exporting increase productivity? A microeconometric analysis of matched firms. Review of International Economics, 12(5), 855-866. Greenaway, D., & Kneller, R. (2004). Exporting and productivity in the United Kingdom. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 20(3), 358-371. Greenaway, D., Gullstrand, J., & Kneller, R. (2005). Exporting may not always boost firm productivity. Review of World Economics, 141(4), 561-582. Heckman, J. J. (1981). Heterogeneity and state dependence. In Studies in labor markets (pp. 91-140). University of Chicago Press. Hitt, M. A., Hoskisson, R. E., & Kim, H. (1997). International diversification: Effects on innovation and firm performance in product-diversified firms. Academy of Management journal, 40(4), 767-798. Kafouros, M. I., Buckley, P. J., Sharp, J. A., & Wang, C. (2008). The role of internationalization in explaining innovation performance. Technovation, 28(1-2), 63-74. Kimura, F., & Kiyota, K. (2006). Exports, FDI, and productivity: Dynamic evidence from Japanese firms. Review of World Economics, 142(4), 695-719. Krugman, P. R. (1979). Increasing returns, monopolistic competition, and international trade. Journal of International Economics, 9(4), 469-479. Leonidou, L. C., Katsikeas, C. S., Palihawadana, D., & Spyropoulou, S. (2007). An analytical review of the factors stimulating smaller firms to export. International Marketing Review. Leuven, E., & Sianesi, B. (2018). PSMATCH2: Stata module to perform full Mahalanobis and propensity score matching, common support graphing, and covariate imbalance testing. Levinsohn, J., & Petrin, A. (2003). Estimating production functions using inputs to control for unobservables. The review of economic studies, 70(2), 317-341. Ma, Y., Tang, H., & Zhang, Y. (2014). Factor intensity, product switching, and productivity: Evidence from Chinese exporters. Journal of International Economics, 92(2), 349-362. Martins, P. S., & Yang, Y. (2009). The impact of exporting on firm productivity: a meta-analysis of the learning-by-exporting hypothesis. Review of World Economics, 145(3), 431-445. Melitz, M. J. (2003). The impact of trade on intra‐industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica, 71(6), 1695-1725. Minetti, R., & Zhu, S. C. (2011). Credit constraints and firm export: Microeconomic evidence from Italy. Journal of International Economics, 83(2), 109-125. Ministry of Investment and Planning (2016). Annual report on enterprises and socio-economic development in 2014-2015. Hanoi: Ministry of Investment and Planning. Monreal-Pérez, J., Aragón-Sánchez, A., & Sánchez-Marín, G. (2012). A longitudinal study of the relationship between export activity and innovation in the Spanish firm: The moderating role of productivity. International Business Review, 21(5), 862- 877. Nguyen, A. N., Pham, N. Q., Nguyen, C. D., & Nguyen, N. D. (2008). Innovation and exports in Vietnam's SME sector. The European Journal of Development Research, 20(2), 262-280. T. H. T. Pham and H. N. Vu /Accounting 6 (2020) 491 Pär, H., & Nan, L. N. (2004). Exports as an Indicator on or Promoter of Successful Swedish Manufacturing Firms in the 1990s. Review of World Economics, 140(3), 415-445. Park, A., Yang, D., Shi, X., & Jiang, Y. (2010). Exporting and firm performance: Chinese exporters and the Asian financial crisis. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 92(4), 822-842. Park, B. I. (2011). Knowledge transfer capacity of multinational enterprises and technology acquisition in international joint ventures. International Business Review, 20(1), 75-87. Pisu, M. (2008). Export destinations and learning-by-exporting: Evidence from Belgium. National Bank of Belgium working paper, (140). Pla-Barber, J., & Alegre, J. (2007). Analysing the link between export intensity, innovation and firm size in a science-based industry. International Business Review, 16(3), 275-293. Ranjan, P., & Raychaudhuri, J. (2011). Self‐selection vs learning: evidence from Indian exporting firms. Indian Growth and Development Review, 4(1), 22-37. Roberts, M. J., & Tybout, J. R. (1997). The decision to export in Colombia: An empirical model of entry with sunk costs. The American Economic Review, 545-564. Rosenbaum, P. R., & Rubin, D. B. (1983). The central role of the propensity score in observational studies for causal effects. Biometrika, 70(1), 41-55. Silva, A., Afonso, Ó., & Africano, A. P. (2010). Do Portuguese manufacturing firms learn by exporting? (No. 373). Universidade do Porto, Faculdade de Economia do Porto. Tomiura, E. (2007). Foreign outsourcing, exporting, and FDI: A productivity comparison at the firm level. Journal of International Economics, 72(1), 113-127. VCCI. 2017. Annual Report on Vietnamese Business 2016. Hanoi: Information and Communications Publishing House. Vu, H., Lim, S., Holmes, M., & Doan, T. (2013). Firm Exporting and Employee Benefits: First Evidence from Vietnam Manufacturing SMEs. Economics Bulletin, 33(1), 519-535. Vu, H. N., & Hoang, B. T. (2020). Business environment and innovation persistence: the case of small-and medium-sized enterprises in Vietnam. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, https://doi.org/10.1080/10438599.2019.1689597 Wagner, J. (2007). Exports and productivity: A survey of the evidence from firm‐level data. World Economy, 30(1), 60-82. Wagner, J. (2012). International trade and firm performance: a survey of empirical studies since 2006. Review of World Economics, 148(2), 235-267. Wernerfelt, B. (1984). A resource‐based view of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, 5(2), 171-180. World Bank (2019). The Wold Bank. Retrieved 06 01, 2017, from data.worldbank.org: https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.DEFL.ZS?locations=VN Appendix A Bernard and Jensen (1995, 1999, 2004) started with a simple case with one time period and no entry cost, the profit function it of firm i at time period t is as below: it (Xt, Zit) = pt . qit* - cit (Xt, Zit| qit*) Eq. (A.1) where qit* is the optimal quantity produced if a firm exports; cit is the cost of producing quantity qit*; pt is the selling price of goods in the foreign market; Xt is the vector of exogenous factors that affect production of the firm such as exchange rate, export promotion regimes; Zit is a vector of all endogenous or firm-specific factors that have influence on profitability such as productivity, size, age, labor quality, innovation. If an expected profit of exporting is equal to or greater than zero, a firm will export. Otherwise, it remains serving the domestic market only. Denoting Yit as firm i’s export status at time t, then Yit =1 if it 0 and Yit =0 if it<0. In the multiple periods case, let represent a single discounting rate, then expected profit of a firm becomes: it (Xt, Zit) = Et ( ) Eq. (A.2) As long as the cost function of today production does not depend on production in previous periods, then the expected profit function in the multi-period case is similar to the single period case. Otherwise, the current export status will have effects on future export status and the value function of the optimizing problem is as follow: ( it. Yit + . Et [Vit+1(.)|q*it] ) Eq. (A.3) A firm will export in period t if the following inequality satisfies: it + . Et[Vit+1 (.) | q*it>0] > . Et[Vit+1 (.) | q*it=0] Eq. (A.4) s t.[ ps.q*is cis.(Xs, Zis | qis*)] s t Vit (.) max{q*it } 492 Entry costs are denoted by N. It is normal to make an assumption that firm will not have to pay entry costs if they had already exported (i.e. N=0 if Yit-1=1). When making a decision to export, firms understand that if they export today, they might not have to pay entry costs in the future. In a single-period case with entry costs, a firm’s profit is specified as follows: Π௧ᇱ (Xt, Zit, q*it-1) = pt . qit* - cit (Xt, Zit, q*it-1| qit*) – N (1-Yit-1) Eq. (A.5) This means firms do not have to pay entry cost if they exported in the previous periods, i.e. Yit-1=1. Firms will export if expected profits minus entry costs are positive. It means Yit=1 if Π௧ᇱ >0. In a multi-period case with entry costs, firms choose a sequence of output levels, , that maximizes current and discounted future profit. It means it = Et ( s-t [Π௦ᇱ .Yis]), where in the single-period Π௦ᇱ is non-negative as firms have an option of not exporting. With a value function as represented below: (Π௧ᇱ . [q*it >0]+ . Et [Vit+1(.)|q*it]) Eq. (A.6) Firm i will export in time t if expected profit net any entry costs is greater than zero as follows: pt . qit*+ . (Et[Vit+1 (.) | q*it>0] - Et[Vit+1 (.) | q*it=0]) - cit (Xt, Zit, q*it-1| qit*) – N (1-Yit-1) >0 Eq. (A.7) Or pt . qit*+ . (Et[Vit+1 (.) | q*it>0] - Et[Vit+1 (.) | q*it=0]) > cit (Xt, Zit, q*it-1| qit*) + N (1-Yit-1) Eq. (A.8) If we define Π௧∗ = pt . qit*+ . (Et[Vit+1 (.) | q*it>0] - Et[Vit+1 (.) | q*it=0]), the decision to export by firm is given by the following discrete choice equation: 𝑌௧ = ൜1 𝑖𝑓 Π௧∗ − 𝑐௧ − 𝑁(1 − 𝑌௧ିଵ) 00 𝑜𝑡ℎ𝑒𝑟𝑤𝑖𝑠𝑒 Eq. (A.9) According to Roberts and Tybout (1997), a method of non-structural binary choice can be used to estimate the decision to export with the following empirical model: 𝑌௧ = ቄ1 𝑖𝑓 𝛽𝑋௧ 𝛾𝑍௧ − 𝑁(1 − 𝑌௧ିଵ) 𝜀௧ 00 𝑜𝑡ℎ𝑒𝑟𝑤𝑖𝑠𝑒 Eq. (A.10) © 2020 by the authors; licensee Growing Science, Canada. This is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC-BY) license ( {qit *}s t s t Vit (.) max{q*it }
File đính kèm:
- a_longitudinal_study_of_self_selection_learning_by_exporting.pdf